Revised: 21 March 2013
In the 2010 Australian federal election*
there was no clear result at the end of vote counting despite the ALP winning
the two party preferred (2PP) vote. In
the end, an ALP minority government was formed after post election negotiations
with the Greens and independents. The
LNP could have quite easily ended up as the government despite losing the 2PP
vote.
By contrast, in the 2012 Queensland state
election, the LNP gained a very clear majority of seats after clearly winning
the 2PP vote. The problem here was that the
ALP won only 8 % of the seats (7 members) despite having 27% of the primary
vote. As a result, the ALP is struggling
to hold the government to account let alone provide a credible alternative at the
next election. Not a good outcome for the state. (The LNP won 88% of the parliamentary seats
despite winning less than 50% of the primary vote.)
The common link between both these problems
is that single member electorates were used to decide who will become members
of parliament. The above are not the
only problems associated with single member electorates.
In this article it is argued that a specific system
based on two member electorates would overcome the problems that are a feature
of systems based on single member electorates.
(*Definitions
of the terms used here are included at the end of the article.)
INTRODUCTION:
Two electoral systems are used in Australia
for state and federal parliaments. For all lower houses of parliament except Tasmania systems
based on single member electorates using some form of simple preference
counting are used. For the Australian Senate and some state upper houses,
systems based on multiple member electorates using some form of proportional
preference counting are used. (The lower houses determine who the
government will be while the upper houses act as houses of review with the
power to reject most legislation.)
Single Member Electorate Systems:
The Queensland state 2012
election results highlight some of the problems associated with single member
electorates. Table 1 provides the key results:
TABLE 1: RESULTS OF QLD 2012 ELECTION
PARTY
|
RESULTS QLD 2012 ELECTION
|
|||
% OF PRIMARY VOTE (@
|
SEATS WITH PARTY LEADING PRIMARY VOTE
|
MEMBERS ELECTED (Actual Result)
|
% OF MEMBERS
|
|
LNP
|
49.7
|
78
|
78
|
87.7
|
ALP
|
26.7
|
7
|
7
|
7.9
|
KAP
|
11.5
|
2
|
2
|
2.2
|
GREENS
|
7.4
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
FAMILY FIRST
|
1.4
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
ONE NATION
|
0.1
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
INDEPENDENTS
|
3.2
|
2
|
2
|
2.2
|
TOTAL
|
100.0
|
89
|
100.0
|
(Details of the Qld electoral system and
the 2012 election results can be found at the Wikapedia
and Qld
electoral commision websites.)
A good result in the sense that the party
that won the 2PP vote was able to form government with a workable majority. A bad result in the sense that the main
opposition party (ALP) will struggle to provide an effective opposition or to
be seen as a credible alternative at the next election because it only won 8%
of the seats. Bad too in that the minor parties only won 2%
of the seats despite winning 20% of the primary vote between them.
The disturbing thing is that the outcome
could have been quite different even if every voter had voted exactly the same. Consider an extreme example: If the
ALP had been able to locate all of its supporters in electorates where the ALP
vote was slightly above 50%, the ALP would have won 48 seats and formed
government without needing any preferences. At the other extreme, if the
distribution of votes had been identical for all electorates, the LNP would
have won all the seats after distribution of preferences. Other changes in the geographical distribution
of supporters could have seen minor parties and/or independents holding the
balance of power. Table 1 and these
examples demonstrate why systems based on single member electorates:
1.
Provide no
guarantee that the party that wins the 2PP vote will form government.
2.
Can have results
distorted by the location of electoral boundaries or geographical distribution
of supporters.
3.
Tend to give the
parties with high primary votes a disproportionate share of the members.
There
are a number of other problems with single member electorates including:
1.
Voters in
marginal electorates have far more influence than those in safe electorates.
2.
Not all voters
will be represented by a member of the government. This can make it harder for these voters to
influence government decisions.
3.
Incumbent members
have an advantage over challengers.
The only real
attraction of single member electorates is that each voter shares “their”
member with fewer other voters.
Large
Multi-member Electorate Systems:
Compared with
single member electorates, multi-member electorates combined with the use of
proportional preference voting result in the percentage of members
elected for each party being closer to the percentage of votes received. However:
1.
There is an increased
risk of minor parties and/or independents holding the balance of power. In this case, who forms government will be
decided by negotiations held after the election, not the voters.
2.
It may be harder
for independents running on local issues to be elected.
3.
Each member will
have to look after far more voters.
4.
It will still be
possible for a party that didn’t win the 2PP vote to form government.
5.
The location of
electorate boundaries and geographic distribution of party supporters can still
distort results unless the whole country/state becomes a single electorate.
The combination of large multi-party electorates
with proportional preference voting is good for houses of review (where it is
desirable to avoid the house being dominated by one party) but not appropriate
for lower houses that have to decide which party is to form government.
Two Member Electorates:
Systems based on two member electorates have
the potential to resolve many of the problems listed above. What is described below is one system
that could realize this potential:
Key features of the proposed system:
1.
The government
will be formed by the party* that wins the overall 2PP vote*. (The voters decide
directly who will be the government.)
2.
Each electorate
will have one member belonging to the government party.
3.
The second member
for each electorate will be elected from non-government candidates.
4.
In addition,
there will be a number of “floating members” who do not represent any
electorate. The division of these
floating seats between the parties will aim at bringing the number of
members for each party closer to what they would have won if the whole state
was a single a multi-member electorate using proportional preference
voting.
5.
The use of
this floating member system means that governments will rarely have a majority. To avoid instability and
ensure governments have enough money to do their job, a two thirds majority
will be required to:
a.
Pass a vote of no
confidence.
b.
Block supply.
c.
Block the setting
up of a government loan
d.
Remove a tax. or
government charge.
e.
Prevent the
government changing an existing government charge the rate for an existing tax.
6. Apart from the above exceptions, a simple majority of MP's will have the power to reject proposed legislation as well as initiate and pass legislation. (A limit on the time between passing legislation and signing it into law would be required to ensure governments cannot use procrastination as a defacto veto.)
7. Vacancies will normally be filled by the nominee of the party the departed member was a candidate for at the time of the last election (or the nominated successor of an independent.) By-elections will only be held if it is not clear who the replacement should be.
7. Vacancies will normally be filled by the nominee of the party the departed member was a candidate for at the time of the last election (or the nominated successor of an independent.) By-elections will only be held if it is not clear who the replacement should be.
The above
will allow a single house parliamentary system to provide both government
stability and the checks and balances that we get from the federal Senate.
*NOTES:
- In this section, the term “party” includes coalitions registered before the election.
- A party that were not in the final 2PP count may challenge the result. The challenging party would form government if it can beat all interested parties in a one on one 2PP count.
The following vote
counting procedure could be used to achieve the key features:
1.
Step 1: Reduce
the number of candidates for each party to one: If a party has more than one candidate for an
electorate, the normal preference vote counting procedure will be used to
determine which candidate will represent the party. (Only ballot papers that
gave their first preference vote to the relevant party will be part of this
count.) The preferences of losing candidates will then be distributed and these
losing candidates excluded from the rest of the count.
2.
Step 2: Do the
overall 2PP count to determine which party will govern.
a.
Preferences of
independents will be distributed first.
b.
The party (not
individual) with the least number of total votes for the state will then be
eliminated and their preferences distributed.
c.
Count will
proceed until only two parties are left.
The party with the most votes at this stage will win the 2PP vote and
form government.
3.
Step 3: Determine
who the non-government member for each electorate will be:
a.
Exclude from this
count all ballot papers that gave their first preference to the government
party.
b.
Use the normal single electorate preference
counting method to determine who the second members will be.
4.
Step 4: Determine
who the floating members will be:
a.
Do a proportional
preference count for the whole state to determine how many members each party
would have got under this system.
b.
For each party
calculate the difference between the proportional number and the numbers calculated
in steps 2 and 3.
c.
Allocate to the
government the number of seats required to bring total government seats up to
what the government would have got under the proportional preference count.
d.
Allocate another
floating seat to the government to compensate for having to supply the speaker. (Only if the government does supply speaker.)
e.
Allocate one
floating member to the non government parties.
i.
Eliminate parties
that already have all the members they would get under proportional preference
voting.
ii.
Allocate one
floating member to the party requiring the largest number of extra members.
iii.
Allocate one
floating member to the party requiring the next largest number of extra
members. Continue this process until all
the parties requiring extra members have received one extra member or all the
floating member vacancies have been filled.
iv.
Repeat steps i to
iii until al the floating vacancies have been filled.
DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS:
The two member electorate system proposed here
reduces most of the problems associated with Australia ’s
single member electorate systems. In
particular, the new system guarantees that:
1.
The party that
wins the 2PP will form a stable government on its own with the power to raise the funds it
needs to do the job.
2.
The system will
provide Senate style checks and balances unless the government has a majority in its own right. This would only happen if there had been a very strong vote in the government's favour (such as occurred in the 2012 Qld election.)
3.
There will be a
viable opposition.
4.
The result will
be fairer to minor parties.
5.
Independents with
strong local support can still become members.
6.
Each electorate
will have one government and one non-government member.
7.
The votes in
every seat are equally important
Most important of all, the location of
electoral boundaries and the geographical distribution of party supporters have
no effect on who wins government and a limited effect on the number of seats won
by each of the non-government parties.
Table 2 compares the actual result of the
2012 Qld election with estimated results if the proposed system had been used
with 29 floating seats.
TABLE 2: COMPARISON EXISTING AND
PROPOSED SYSTEM
PARTY
|
RESULTS QLD 2012 ELECTION
|
ESTIMATED MEMBERS USING PROPORTIONAL PREFERENCE (WHOLE STATE A SINGLE ELECTORATE)
|
ESTIMATE
PROPOSED SYSTEM
|
||
% OF PRIMARY VOTE (@
|
MEMBERS (Actual Result)
|
FLOATING MEMBERS
|
TOTAL MEMBERS
|
||
LNP
|
49.7
|
78
|
46
|
17
|
47
|
ALP
|
26.7
|
7
|
24
|
0
|
25
|
KAP
|
11.5
|
2
|
10
|
6
|
8
|
GREENS
|
7.4
|
0
|
6
|
3
|
6
|
FAMILY FIRST
|
1.4
|
0
|
1
|
1
|
1
|
ONE NATION
|
0.1
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
3.2
|
2
|
2
|
0
|
2
|
|
TOTAL
|
100.0
|
89
|
89
|
29
|
89
|
*NOTES:
1.
The Qld
parliament had 89 members after the 2012 election..
2.
Estimates are based
on primary votes only, not on a detailed analysis of the 2012 result.
3.
It is unusual for
a government to get as high as 49.7 % of the primary vote. The LNP would have lost its parliamentary majority
if their primary vote dropped to 47.4%.
4. Qld has 30 federal electorates, the same as the number of shared electorates assumed for the table 2.
4. Qld has 30 federal electorates, the same as the number of shared electorates assumed for the table 2.
There are numerous variations on what is
proposed here. Consideration might be given to:
1.
Allowing parties that were not in the final 2PP count to challenge the result. The challenging party would form government if it can beat all other interested parties in a one
on one 2PP count. (The challenging party wins
because a majority of voters prefer it to any other individual party –
Could quite easily happen if the smaller party is a center party that receives most of the preferences of other parties.) Parties with primary votes below some cut-off might be excluded from this challenge process.
2.
Guarantee that total
members for the main opposition party will be at least the same as the number
of electorates. This would help this
party compete against the government in the next election by being able to
allocate a member to each electorate. Other non-government parties may lose
members to allow this to be done unless the extra main opposition party members
were additional, non-voting members of parliament.
The crucial features of any good system will
be:
1.
Government is
formed by the party (or registered coalition) that wins the overall 2PP vote.
2.
Each electorate
ends up with a government and non-government member.
DEFINITIONS:
Ballot paper: Voters record their vote on their ballot paper and place it in a ballot
box for counting.
Coalition: An
alliance between two or more political parties.
Federal government: The national government.
Incumbent: A
candidate who was the member for the seat before the election.
Independent:
A candidate who is not the official candidate of a political party.
Lower house: The house of parliament that decides which party/coalition forms
government. Both upper and lower houses
have the right to initiate legislation.
Upper House:
This is a house of review that should act as a check and balance. With the
possible exception of some money bills legislation needs to be passed by both
houses of parliament. Queensland has no
upper house.
Preference voting: The system used for all government elections in Australia .
It allows voters to show their support for minor parties without losing their
right to vote for their preferred major party. Voters put number one next to the name of
their preferred candidate (first preference), two next to their second
preference etc. (Some states allow
symbols other than numbers to be used.)
Primary vote: This is the total number of first preferences received by a
candidate or party.
Counting preference votes for single
member electorates: The number of first preference
votes received by each candidate are counted.
If no candidate has more than 50% of the vote, the candidate with the
least number of votes is eliminated and the second preferences of this candidate
are added to the votes of the surviving candidates. This process continues
until one candidate gets more than 50% of the votes. For more details see Counting for the
Federal House of Representatives.
Proportional preference systems: These systems are used for counting preference votes in multimember
electorates such as those used for the Australian Senate. For details see How the Senate
Votes are Counted
Two party preferred vote (2PP): This count can be done for both individual electorates or the
overall vote. For the overall vote:
At the start of this count all candidates who are not party candidates will be
eliminated and their preferences distributed.
The candidates for the party with the least number of votes in the
overall count will then be eliminated and their preferences distributed. This procedure will continue until there are
only two parties left. The 2PP vote is the votes (including received
preferences that the surviving two parties have at this stage.)
Major parties: These are the parties that have a real chance of forming government.
For many years, control at national and state level has alternated between the
ALP and a stable coalition of the Liberal and National parties. In Queensland , the
Liberal and National parties merged to form the LNP before the 2012
election.
Minority government: A term used to describe a government that depends on independents
or minor parties to retain power.
Safe seats: Seats
that one party wins every election.
Working majority: A majority large for the government to get its
legislation passed. A government needs at least one more members than the
combined non-government members to have a working majority. One government
member usually becomes the parliamentary speaker. The speaker only has a
casting vote
No comments:
Post a Comment